Monday, June 20, 2016

Why is the demand curve perfectly elastic in perfect competition?

Under perfect competition, the aggregate demand for a good or service will rise in response to a lower price. The lower the price the higher the aggregate demand will be, all other things being held equal. Conversely, the higher the price the lower the aggregate demand will be. The elasticity or responsiveness of the demand curve is accordingly held to be perfect in theory. In other words, the demand curve will move outward or inward on the x axis with perfect responsiveness to changes in price. This is an assumption built into a simplifying classical economic model in order to make explicit the behavior of certain economic variables one wishes to test. All simplifying assumptions in such models are understood to be useful mathematical rules of thumb and not absolute expressions of economic reality in every case. Veblen goods are an obvious exception to perfect price elasticity as their demand increases with higher prices.


The question considers why in perfect competition the demand curve is assumed to be perfectly elastic. More specifically, this assumption refers to the firm’s demand curve in a perfectly competitive market, rather than the overall demand curve for the market as a whole. 
The first step is to define the term elasticity. This is a mathematical concept relating quantity demanded to price. Specifically, it is defined as the percent change in quantity (demanded) divided by the percent change in price. As such it is mathematically related to slope, but is not equivalent. “Perfect” elasticity is applied to the situation in which the demand curve is horizontal, i.e. slope = 0. Mathematically, this would imply that the amount of output which the firm may sell at the given market price is effectively infinite. More accurately, the firm may sell all of the output of which it is currently capable at the given market price. 
The key feature of this situation is that the firm is a perfect price taker, rather than price maker. That is, offering output at a price lower than “market” would not result in additional sales, and offering it at a price higher than market would result in no sales whatsoever (i.e. all buyers would simply go elsewhere rather than pay the higher price). In a perfectly competitive market, ALL firms are in this same situation. The market price is established, at equilibrium, by the cumulative interaction of all buyers and all sellers in some type of auction/open market process. This requires that the good or service in question is perfectly homogeneous between producers (e.g. wheat of a certain grade) such that one supplier’s output is literally indistinguishable from any others. Other assumptions include that switching from one supplier to another is completely costless for any and all buyers. 
Note that this condition is largely hypothetical. Truly perfect competitive price equilibrium rarely occurs. Most markets are typically in motion, always searching for new equilibrium in reaction to the latest change in conditions. Also, only certain commodities meet the requirement of homogeneity, and suppliers are constantly trying to create the perception if not the reality of product differentiation so that they can, in fact, exercise some control over price.

No comments:

Post a Comment

Why is the fact that the Americans are helping the Russians important?

In the late author Tom Clancy’s first novel, The Hunt for Red October, the assistance rendered to the Russians by the United States is impor...